Skip to main content
Top
Published in: The European Journal of Health Economics 2/2012

01-04-2012 | Original Paper

Malpractice liability, technology choice and negative defensive medicine

Author: Eberhard Feess

Published in: The European Journal of Health Economics | Issue 2/2012

Login to get access

Abstract

We extend the theoretical literature on the impact of malpractice liability by allowing for two treatment technologies, a safe and a risky one. The safe technology bears no failure risk, but leads to patient-specific disutility since it cannot completely solve the health problems. By contrast, the risky technology (for instance a surgery) may entirely cure patients, but fail with some probability depending on the hospital’s care level. Tight malpractice liability increases care levels if the risky technology is chosen at all, but also leads to excessively high incentives for avoiding the liability exposure by adopting the safe technology. We refer to this distortion toward the safe technology as negative defensive medicine. Taking the problem of negative defensive medicine seriously, the second best optimal liability needs to balance between the over-incentive for the safe technology in case of tough liability and the incentive to adopt little care for the risky technology in case of weak liability. In a model with errors in court, we find that gross negligence where hospitals are held liable only for very low care levels outperforms standard negligence, even though standard negligence would implement the first best efficient care level.
Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See e.g. the famous Harvard-study [33] and the comment by Hyman [19].
 
2
See e.g. Boehm [3] for suggestions in this direction.
 
3
See e.g. Kessler and McClellan [25].
 
4
See e.g. Localio et al. [31] and Dubay et al. [12].
 
5
The problem could only have been solved by signing a complete contract, which is obviously impossible in our context, though. Consequently, Arlen and McLeod [1] use an incomplete contract approach to analyze malpractice liability.
 
6
See e.g. Cohen and Eisenberg [5] for a discussion of high liability risks in these cases.
 
7
By slight abuse of terminology, we subsequently use “treatment” and “technology” synonymously.
 
8
See our literature review below.
 
9
“Care” does not necessarily refer to a doctor’s effort during a surgery, for instance, but also to the organization of processes in the hospital. In fact, Rogers et al. [35] find in a case study of 444 malpractice claims that communication breakdowns were responsible in around one quarter of all observations. They point out that malpractice claims should be used much more intensively as information sources in finding out where malpractice comes from; see also Studdert et al. [40, p. 287].
 
10
For instance, the Hospital Quality Alliance (HQA) in the US has designed pay-for-performance programs by defining best practice based on individual and composite measures for heart failure, acute myocardial infarction and pneumonia, and there is econometric evidence that hospitals taking part in the program have higher quality improvements; see e.g. Lindenauer et al. [30] and Werner et al. [43]. The authors admit that controlling for self-selection issues is difficult, though.
 
11
See e.g. Kessler et al. [27, p. 2619] for a brief overview on factors influencing expected damages for malpractice.
 
12
See e.g. Boumil et al. [4].
 
13
See e.g. Faure and Koziol [14] and Kennedy and Grubb [22].
 
14
See e.g. National Practitioner Data Bank (NPDB) [34], and U.S. Department of Health and Human Services [42].
 
15
For an earlier comprehensive overview on the theoretical and empirical literature see Danzon [9], and for an assessment of the situation from a legal point of view see Hyman and Silver [20].
 
16
We are grateful to an anonymous referee who has pointed to this artifact of the discrete modeling that we used in a former working paper version of this article.
 
17
Assuming that the patient’s disutility from the safe technology is independent of the hospital’s care level normalized to zero is without loss of generality. All we need is that the patient’s health reacts more sensitively to the hospital’s care under the risky technology. As mentioned in the introduction, it is not crucial for our results that the hospital can perfectly observe the patient’s disutility θ; all that is required is an informative signal.
 
18
See our discussion in the concluding section.
 
19
One might wonder if non-liability costs should be part of the social cost function as part of these costs may be purely re-distributional. This will be discussed in the concluding section. Our results are qualitatively independent of whether α enters the social cost function or not, though.
 
20
As usual in the literature on liability, “costs” include both monetary terms such as treatment expenditures (x in our case) and the monetary equivalents of preference costs from the patient’s harm or from the doctors’ empathy for patients (1 + α in our case).
 
21
For x < q, the uniform distribution causes the artifact that courts could receive signals on negative care, τ < 0. This can easily be avoided by assuming instead that the probability mass is centered on zero which yields identical results.
 
22
Implicitly, we hence assume that proving causation is no issue. See our discussion in the concluding section.
 
23
As usual, gross negligence is defined as a negligence standard below ordinary negligence, i.e. as a rule where liability is only confirmed for very low care levels.
 
24
These similarities and differences of causation standards and negligence standards in a general model with asymmetric information have recently been analyzed by Feess et al. [17].
 
Literature
1.
go back to reference Arlen, J., Mac Leod, W.B.: Malpractice liability for physicians and managed care organizations. N. Y. Univ. Law Rev. 78(6), 1929–2006 (2003) Arlen, J., Mac Leod, W.B.: Malpractice liability for physicians and managed care organizations. N. Y. Univ. Law Rev. 78(6), 1929–2006 (2003)
2.
go back to reference Baicker, K., Chandra, A.: The effect of malpractice liability on the delivery of health care. Forum. Health Econ. Policy 8(4), (2005) Baicker, K., Chandra, A.: The effect of malpractice liability on the delivery of health care. Forum. Health Econ. Policy 8(4), (2005)
3.
go back to reference Boehm, G.: Debunking medical malpractice myths: unraveling the false premises behind “tort reform”. Yale J. Health Policy Law Ethics 5(1), 357–369 (2005)PubMed Boehm, G.: Debunking medical malpractice myths: unraveling the false premises behind “tort reform”. Yale J. Health Policy Law Ethics 5(1), 357–369 (2005)PubMed
4.
go back to reference Boumil, M., Elias, C., Moes, D.: Medical Liability in a Nutshell. Thomson West, St. Paul (2003) Boumil, M., Elias, C., Moes, D.: Medical Liability in a Nutshell. Thomson West, St. Paul (2003)
5.
go back to reference Cohen, M.H., Eisenberg, D.: Potential physician malpractice liability associated with complementary and integrative medical therapies. Ann. Intern. Med. 136(8), 596–603 (2002)PubMed Cohen, M.H., Eisenberg, D.: Potential physician malpractice liability associated with complementary and integrative medical therapies. Ann. Intern. Med. 136(8), 596–603 (2002)PubMed
6.
go back to reference Craswell, R., Calfee, J.: Deterrence and uncertain legal standards. J. Law Econ. Organiz. 2(2), 279–303 (1986) Craswell, R., Calfee, J.: Deterrence and uncertain legal standards. J. Law Econ. Organiz. 2(2), 279–303 (1986)
7.
go back to reference Danzon, P.: Liability and liability insurance for medical malpractice. J. Health Econ. 4, 309–331 (1985)PubMedCrossRef Danzon, P.: Liability and liability insurance for medical malpractice. J. Health Econ. 4, 309–331 (1985)PubMedCrossRef
8.
go back to reference Danzon, P.: Alternative liability regimes for medical injuries: evidence from simulation analysis. J. Risk Insur. 61(2), 219–244 (1994)CrossRef Danzon, P.: Alternative liability regimes for medical injuries: evidence from simulation analysis. J. Risk Insur. 61(2), 219–244 (1994)CrossRef
9.
go back to reference Danzon, P.: Liability for medical malpractice. In: Culyer, A.J., Newhouse, J.P. (eds) Handbooks in Economics, vol. 17. Handbook of Health Economics, pp. 1339–1404. Elsevier, Amsterdam (2000) Danzon, P.: Liability for medical malpractice. In: Culyer, A.J., Newhouse, J.P. (eds) Handbooks in Economics, vol. 17. Handbook of Health Economics, pp. 1339–1404. Elsevier, Amsterdam (2000)
10.
go back to reference Demougin, D., Fluet, C.: Preponderance of the evidence. Eur. Econ. Rev. 50(2), 963–976 (2005) Demougin, D., Fluet, C.: Preponderance of the evidence. Eur. Econ. Rev. 50(2), 963–976 (2005)
11.
12.
go back to reference Dubay, L., Kaestner, R., Waidmann, T.: The impact of malpractice fears on cesarean section rates. J. Health Econ. 18, 491–522 (1999)PubMedCrossRef Dubay, L., Kaestner, R., Waidmann, T.: The impact of malpractice fears on cesarean section rates. J. Health Econ. 18, 491–522 (1999)PubMedCrossRef
13.
go back to reference Ewert, R.: Auditor liability and the precision of auditing standards. J. Inst. Theor. Econ. 155, 181–206 (1999) Ewert, R.: Auditor liability and the precision of auditing standards. J. Inst. Theor. Econ. 155, 181–206 (1999)
14.
go back to reference Faure, M., Koziol, H.: Cases on Medical Malpractice in a Comparative Perspective, Tort and Insurance Law. Springer, Berlin (2001)CrossRef Faure, M., Koziol, H.: Cases on Medical Malpractice in a Comparative Perspective, Tort and Insurance Law. Springer, Berlin (2001)CrossRef
15.
go back to reference Feess, E., Ossig, S.: Reimbursement schemes for hospitals, malpractice liability, and intrinsic motivation. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 27(4), 423–441 (2007)CrossRef Feess, E., Ossig, S.: Reimbursement schemes for hospitals, malpractice liability, and intrinsic motivation. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 27(4), 423–441 (2007)CrossRef
16.
go back to reference Feess, E., Muehlheusser, G., Wohlschlegel, A.: Environmental liability under uncertain causation. Eur. J. Law Econ. 28(2), 133–148 (2009a)CrossRef Feess, E., Muehlheusser, G., Wohlschlegel, A.: Environmental liability under uncertain causation. Eur. J. Law Econ. 28(2), 133–148 (2009a)CrossRef
17.
go back to reference Feess, E., Muehlheusser, G., Wohlschlegel, A.: Screening in courts: on the joint use of negligence and causation standards. J. Law Econ. Organiz. (forthcoming) (2009b) Feess, E., Muehlheusser, G., Wohlschlegel, A.: Screening in courts: on the joint use of negligence and causation standards. J. Law Econ. Organiz. (forthcoming) (2009b)
18.
go back to reference Gal-Or, E.: Optimal reimbursement and malpractice sharing rules in health care markets. J. Regul. Econ. 16, 237–265 (1999)CrossRef Gal-Or, E.: Optimal reimbursement and malpractice sharing rules in health care markets. J. Regul. Econ. 16, 237–265 (1999)CrossRef
19.
go back to reference Hyman, D.A.: Medical malpractice: what do we know and what (if anything) should we do about it? Texas Law Rev. (June 1), 1639–1655 (2002) Hyman, D.A.: Medical malpractice: what do we know and what (if anything) should we do about it? Texas Law Rev. (June 1), 1639–1655 (2002)
20.
go back to reference Hyman, D.A., Silver, C.: The poor state of health care quality in the U.S.: is malpractice liability part of the problem or part of the solution?. Cornell Law Rev. 90(4), 893–993 (2005)PubMed Hyman, D.A., Silver, C.: The poor state of health care quality in the U.S.: is malpractice liability part of the problem or part of the solution?. Cornell Law Rev. 90(4), 893–993 (2005)PubMed
21.
go back to reference Katz, D.A., Williams, G.C., Brown, R.L., Aufderheide, T.P., Bogner, M., Rahko, P.S. et al.: Emergency physicians’ fear of malpractice in evaluating patients with possible acute cardiac ischemia. Ann. Emerg. Med. 46(6) (2005) Katz, D.A., Williams, G.C., Brown, R.L., Aufderheide, T.P., Bogner, M., Rahko, P.S. et al.: Emergency physicians’ fear of malpractice in evaluating patients with possible acute cardiac ischemia. Ann. Emerg. Med. 46(6) (2005)
22.
go back to reference Kennedy, I., Grubb, A.: Medical Law, 3rd edn. Butterworths, London (2000) Kennedy, I., Grubb, A.: Medical Law, 3rd edn. Butterworths, London (2000)
23.
go back to reference Kessler, D.P., McClellan, M.B.: Do doctors practice defensive medicine. Q. J. Econ. 111, 353–390 (1996)CrossRef Kessler, D.P., McClellan, M.B.: Do doctors practice defensive medicine. Q. J. Econ. 111, 353–390 (1996)CrossRef
24.
go back to reference Kessler, D.P., McClellan, M.B.: The effects of malpractice pressure and liability reforms on physicians’ perceptions of medical care. Law Contemp. Probl. 60, 81–106 (1997)CrossRef Kessler, D.P., McClellan, M.B.: The effects of malpractice pressure and liability reforms on physicians’ perceptions of medical care. Law Contemp. Probl. 60, 81–106 (1997)CrossRef
25.
go back to reference Kessler, D.P., McClellan, M.B.: How liability law affects medical productivity. J. Health Econ. 21, 931–955 (2002)PubMedCrossRef Kessler, D.P., McClellan, M.B.: How liability law affects medical productivity. J. Health Econ. 21, 931–955 (2002)PubMedCrossRef
26.
go back to reference Kessler, D.P., McClellan, M.B.: Malpractice law and health care reform: optimal liability policy in an era of managed care. J. Public Econ. 84, 175–197 (2002)CrossRef Kessler, D.P., McClellan, M.B.: Malpractice law and health care reform: optimal liability policy in an era of managed care. J. Public Econ. 84, 175–197 (2002)CrossRef
27.
go back to reference Kessler, D.P., Sage, W.M., Becker, D.J.: Impact of malpractice reforms on the supply of physician services. J. Am. Med. Assoc. 293(21), 2618–2625 (2005)CrossRef Kessler, D.P., Sage, W.M., Becker, D.J.: Impact of malpractice reforms on the supply of physician services. J. Am. Med. Assoc. 293(21), 2618–2625 (2005)CrossRef
28.
go back to reference Kessler, D.P., Summerton, N., Graham, J.R.: Effects of the medical liability system in Australia, the UK, and the USA. Lancet 368, 240–246 (2006)PubMedCrossRef Kessler, D.P., Summerton, N., Graham, J.R.: Effects of the medical liability system in Australia, the UK, and the USA. Lancet 368, 240–246 (2006)PubMedCrossRef
29.
go back to reference Kolstad, C.D., Ulen, T.S., Johnson, G.V.: Ex post liabiliy for harm vs. ex ante safety regulation: substitutes or complements. Am. Econ. Rev. 80(4), 888–901 (1990) Kolstad, C.D., Ulen, T.S., Johnson, G.V.: Ex post liabiliy for harm vs. ex ante safety regulation: substitutes or complements. Am. Econ. Rev. 80(4), 888–901 (1990)
30.
go back to reference Lindenauer, P.K., Remus, D., Roman, S., Rothberg, M.B., Benjamin, E.M., Ma, A. et al.: Public reporting and pay for performance in hospital quality improvement. N. Engl. J.Med. 356(5), 486–496 (2007)PubMedCrossRef Lindenauer, P.K., Remus, D., Roman, S., Rothberg, M.B., Benjamin, E.M., Ma, A. et al.: Public reporting and pay for performance in hospital quality improvement. N. Engl. J.Med. 356(5), 486–496 (2007)PubMedCrossRef
31.
go back to reference Localio, A.R., Lawthers, A.G., Bengtson, J.M., Hebert, L.E., Weaver, S.L., Brennan, T.A. et al.: Relationship between malpractice claims and cesarean delivery. J. Am. Med. Assoc. 269(3), 366–373 (1993)CrossRef Localio, A.R., Lawthers, A.G., Bengtson, J.M., Hebert, L.E., Weaver, S.L., Brennan, T.A. et al.: Relationship between malpractice claims and cesarean delivery. J. Am. Med. Assoc. 269(3), 366–373 (1993)CrossRef
33.
go back to reference Mello, M.M., Brennan, T.A.: Deterrence of medical errors: theory and evidence for malpractice reform. Tex. Law Rev. 80, 1595–1637 (2002) Mello, M.M., Brennan, T.A.: Deterrence of medical errors: theory and evidence for malpractice reform. Tex. Law Rev. 80, 1595–1637 (2002)
34.
go back to reference National Practitioner Data Bank Annual Report (NPDB) (ed.): U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Health Resources and Services Administration (2002) National Practitioner Data Bank Annual Report (NPDB) (ed.): U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Health Resources and Services Administration (2002)
35.
go back to reference Rogers, S.O., Gawande, A.A., Kwaan, M., Puopolo, A.L., Yoon, C., Brennan, T.A. et al.: Analysis of surgical errors in closed malpractice claims at 4 liability insurers. Surgery 140(1), 25–33 (2006)PubMedCrossRef Rogers, S.O., Gawande, A.A., Kwaan, M., Puopolo, A.L., Yoon, C., Brennan, T.A. et al.: Analysis of surgical errors in closed malpractice claims at 4 liability insurers. Surgery 140(1), 25–33 (2006)PubMedCrossRef
36.
go back to reference Schwartz, R.: Auditors’ liability, vague due care and auditing standards. Rev. Quant. Finance Account. 11, 183–207 (1998)CrossRef Schwartz, R.: Auditors’ liability, vague due care and auditing standards. Rev. Quant. Finance Account. 11, 183–207 (1998)CrossRef
37.
go back to reference Shavell, S.: Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law. Harvard University Press, Boston (2004) Shavell, S.: Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law. Harvard University Press, Boston (2004)
38.
go back to reference Sobel, D.L., Loughlin, K.R., Coogan, C.L.: Medical malpractice liability in clinical urology: a survey of practicing urologists. J. Urol. 175, 1847–1851 (2006)PubMedCrossRef Sobel, D.L., Loughlin, K.R., Coogan, C.L.: Medical malpractice liability in clinical urology: a survey of practicing urologists. J. Urol. 175, 1847–1851 (2006)PubMedCrossRef
39.
go back to reference Studdert, D.M., Mello, M.M., Brennan, T.A.: Medical malpractice. N. Engl. J. Med. 350(3), 283–292 (2004)PubMedCrossRef Studdert, D.M., Mello, M.M., Brennan, T.A.: Medical malpractice. N. Engl. J. Med. 350(3), 283–292 (2004)PubMedCrossRef
40.
go back to reference Studdert, D.M., Mello, M.M., Gawande, A.A., Gandhi, T.K., Kachalia, A., Catherine Yoon, C. et al.: Claims, errors, and compensation payments in medical malpractice litigation. N. Engl. J. Med. 354(19), 2024–2033 (2006)PubMedCrossRef Studdert, D.M., Mello, M.M., Gawande, A.A., Gandhi, T.K., Kachalia, A., Catherine Yoon, C. et al.: Claims, errors, and compensation payments in medical malpractice litigation. N. Engl. J. Med. 354(19), 2024–2033 (2006)PubMedCrossRef
41.
go back to reference Studdert, D.M., Mello, M.M., Sage, W.M., DesRoches, C.M., Peugh, J., Zapert, K. et al.: Defensive medicine among high-risk specialist physicians in a volatile malpractice environment. J. Am. Med. Assoc. 293(21), 2609–2617 (2005)CrossRef Studdert, D.M., Mello, M.M., Sage, W.M., DesRoches, C.M., Peugh, J., Zapert, K. et al.: Defensive medicine among high-risk specialist physicians in a volatile malpractice environment. J. Am. Med. Assoc. 293(21), 2609–2617 (2005)CrossRef
42.
go back to reference U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (ed.): Confronting the new health care crisis: improving health care quality and lowering costs by fixing our medical liability system (2002) U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (ed.): Confronting the new health care crisis: improving health care quality and lowering costs by fixing our medical liability system (2002)
43.
go back to reference Werner, R.M., Goldman, L.E., Dudley, R.A.: Comparisons of change in quality of care between safety-net and non-safety-net hospitals. J. Am. Med. Assoc. 299(18), 1–16 (2008)CrossRef Werner, R.M., Goldman, L.E., Dudley, R.A.: Comparisons of change in quality of care between safety-net and non-safety-net hospitals. J. Am. Med. Assoc. 299(18), 1–16 (2008)CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Malpractice liability, technology choice and negative defensive medicine
Author
Eberhard Feess
Publication date
01-04-2012
Publisher
Springer-Verlag
Published in
The European Journal of Health Economics / Issue 2/2012
Print ISSN: 1618-7598
Electronic ISSN: 1618-7601
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-010-0294-7

Other articles of this Issue 2/2012

The European Journal of Health Economics 2/2012 Go to the issue