Skip to main content
Top
Published in: PharmacoEconomics 2/2004

01-10-2004 | Original Research Article

The economics of follow-on drug research and development

Trends in entry rates and the timing of development

Authors: Joseph A. DiMasi, Ph.D., Cherie Paquette

Published in: PharmacoEconomics | Special Issue 2/2004

Login to get access

Abstract

Objectives: The development of so-called ‘me-too’, or ‘follow-on’, drugs by the pharmaceutical industry has been viewed by some as duplicative and wasteful, while others have argued that these drugs often provide needed therapeutic options and inject some price competition into the marketplace. This study examines data on the trends in the speed with which competitive entry has occurred in the pharmaceutical marketplace and the competitive nature of the industry’s development of these drugs.
Data and methods: We examined data on the entry rates of drugs in a large number of therapeutic classes over time, as well as detailed survey information on the relative timing of the development of drugs in the classes. Classes were defined according to chemical structure or pharmacologic mode of action and similarity of clinical use. We determined average times to initial and subsequent entry in drug classes by period and examined the timing of development milestones achieved by what have turned out to be follow-on drugs in relation to the development and approval of the first drug in a class to be approved.
Results: We found that the period of marketing exclusivity that the breakthrough drug in a new class enjoys has fallen dramatically over time (a median of 10.2 years in the 1970s to 1.2 years for the late 1990s). Approximately one-third of follow-on new drugs received a priority rating from the US FDA. The vast majority of the follow-on drugs for drug classes that were created in the last decade were in clinical development prior to the approval of the class breakthrough drug.
Conclusions: The data suggest that entry barriers have fallen over time for new drug introductions. The increased competitiveness of the pharmaceutical marketplace was likely fueled by changes over time on both the supply and demand sides. The development histories of entrants to new drug classes suggest that development races better characterise new drug development than does a model of post hoc imitation. Thus, the usual distinctions drawn between breakthrough and ‘me-too’ drugs may not be very meaningful.
Footnotes
1
Excluded from analysis here are new diagnostic drugs and new salts, esters or formulations of existing drugs.
 
2
We excluded a small number of classes where the same sponsor marketed all entrants. There was no trend in the data in the number of such classes.
 
3
Forty-eight of the first-in-class compounds were approved after the US orphan drug legislation was enacted (4 January 1983). Prior to this legislation, very few drugs were developed for rare diseases and conditions. We include Protropin® as one of the seven drugs. Protropin® did not technically have orphan drug status at the time of regulatory approval. However, the manufacturer had applied for orphan drug designation prior to approval, which it received shortly after approval.
 
4
The 1970s values increase to 10.5 years for the mean and the median if two outlier classes (selective estrogen receptor modulators [SERMS] and rifamycin antibiotics) are included in the analysis. The time to a first follow-on entrant for these classes were 19.4 and 21.6 years, respectively.
 
5
Tradenames are used for identification purposes only and do not imply product endorsement.
 
6
We also examined double logarithmic, semi-logarithmic and polynomial specifications. The linear regression performed as well as some of these forms, and much better than others.
 
7
The rating system is a management tool for the US FDA that is intended to help it better allocate its resources. It is thus not based on a set of standards that necessarily remains fixed over time. If, suddenly, the submissions from industry were all rated priority or all rated standard, then the rating system would cease to be a useful management tool. It is likely then that to some degree, the rating system is endogenous. It is also the case that some drugs prove to be more useful than originally thought after they have been in widespread use for some time.
 
8
Censoring could potentially be an issue here for the more recent periods. However, there is likely even less reason to suspect that it would be a material issue here than it is for time to first entry. Not only has a significant amount of time already elapsed, but also in these cases not just one but multiple competitors are already on the market, thereby further reducing the incentive to develop and market additional entrants to the class.
 
9
The IND results for the 1960s may be somewhat skewed since the US IND process was not initiated until 1963 after the 1962 Amendments to the US Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act of 1938 were enacted. INDs were filed in 1963 for drugs that had already been in clinical testing in the US in prior years. Otherwise, though, the results are conservative since we do not have complete information on the development histories of the drugs.
 
10
In light of growing cost containment pressures, industry managers have suggested to us that firms are increasingly pursuing a best-in-class strategy, in which winning the race is not as important as developing a drug with a particularly attractive clinical or economic profile.
 
11
For example, Relman and Angell[25] state: “FDA regulations should be changed to require that new drug applications include evidence not only of the safety and the efficacy of a new drug, but also of the drug’s effectiveness in relation to existing products of the same type. Approval should depend in part on whether the new drug adds something useful in terms of greater effectiveness, greater safety, fewer side effects, or substantially greater convenience…That policy change alone would dramatically improve the medical value of new prescription drugs, since drug companies would have no incentive to turn out me-too drugs and would have to shift their R&D emphasis to finding more innovative ones.”
 
12
The ALLHAT antihypertensive study was a comparative efficacy trial of certain drugs in a number of antihypertensive classes. This one study took 8 years to complete and cost approximately $US125 million.[28]
 
Literature
1.
go back to reference Wastila LJ, Ulcickas ME, Lasagna L. The World Health Organization’s essential drug list. J Clin Res Drug Dev 1989; 3: 105–15 Wastila LJ, Ulcickas ME, Lasagna L. The World Health Organization’s essential drug list. J Clin Res Drug Dev 1989; 3: 105–15
2.
go back to reference Kemp BA. The follow-on development process and the market for diuretics. In: Helms RB, editor. Drug development and marketing. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute, 1975 Kemp BA. The follow-on development process and the market for diuretics. In: Helms RB, editor. Drug development and marketing. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute, 1975
3.
go back to reference Werthheimer A, Levy R, O’Connor T. Too many drugs? The clinical and economic value of incremental innovations. In: Research in human capital and development. Vol. 14, Investing in Health: The Social and Economic Benefits of Health Care Innovation., Sorkin A, Summers K, Farquhar, eds., Greenwich, Conn: JAI Press, 2001: 77–118CrossRef Werthheimer A, Levy R, O’Connor T. Too many drugs? The clinical and economic value of incremental innovations. In: Research in human capital and development. Vol. 14, Investing in Health: The Social and Economic Benefits of Health Care Innovation., Sorkin A, Summers K, Farquhar, eds., Greenwich, Conn: JAI Press, 2001: 77–118CrossRef
4.
go back to reference Lu ZJ, Comanor WS. Strategic pricing of new pharmaceuticals. Rev Econ Stat 1998; 80 (1): 108–18CrossRef Lu ZJ, Comanor WS. Strategic pricing of new pharmaceuticals. Rev Econ Stat 1998; 80 (1): 108–18CrossRef
5.
go back to reference Towse A, Leighton T. The changing nature of NCE pricing of second and subsequent entrants. In: Sussex J, Marchant N, editors. Risk and return in the pharmaceutical industry. London: Office of Health Economics, 1999 Aug: 91–105 Towse A, Leighton T. The changing nature of NCE pricing of second and subsequent entrants. In: Sussex J, Marchant N, editors. Risk and return in the pharmaceutical industry. London: Office of Health Economics, 1999 Aug: 91–105
8.
go back to reference Agarwal R, Gort M. First-mover advantage and the speed of competitive entry, 1887–1986. J Law Econ 2001; 44 (April): 161–77CrossRef Agarwal R, Gort M. First-mover advantage and the speed of competitive entry, 1887–1986. J Law Econ 2001; 44 (April): 161–77CrossRef
9.
go back to reference Bain JS. Barriers to new competition. Cambridge (MA): Harvard University Press, 1956 Bain JS. Barriers to new competition. Cambridge (MA): Harvard University Press, 1956
10.
go back to reference Kettler HE. Competition through innovation, innovation through competition. London: Office of Health Economics, 1998 Nov Kettler HE. Competition through innovation, innovation through competition. London: Office of Health Economics, 1998 Nov
11.
go back to reference Scrip’s yearbook. Richmond, UK: PJB Publications, 1987–2003 Scrip’s yearbook. Richmond, UK: PJB Publications, 1987–2003
12.
go back to reference Grabowski HG, Vernon J, DiMasi JA. Returns on R&D for 1990s new drug introductions. Pharmacoeconomics 2002; 20 Suppl. 3: 11–29PubMedCrossRef Grabowski HG, Vernon J, DiMasi JA. Returns on R&D for 1990s new drug introductions. Pharmacoeconomics 2002; 20 Suppl. 3: 11–29PubMedCrossRef
13.
go back to reference DiMasi JA, Hansen RW, Grabowski HG. The price of innovation: new estimates of drug development costs. J Health Econ 2003; 22 (2): 151–85PubMedCrossRef DiMasi JA, Hansen RW, Grabowski HG. The price of innovation: new estimates of drug development costs. J Health Econ 2003; 22 (2): 151–85PubMedCrossRef
14.
go back to reference DiMasi JA. Risks in new drug development: approval success rates for investigational drugs. Clin Pharmacol Ther 2001; 69 (5): 297–307PubMedCrossRef DiMasi JA. Risks in new drug development: approval success rates for investigational drugs. Clin Pharmacol Ther 2001; 69 (5): 297–307PubMedCrossRef
15.
go back to reference DiMasi JA. New drug development in the United States: 1963–1999. Clin Pharmacol Ther 2001; 69 (5): 286–96PubMedCrossRef DiMasi JA. New drug development in the United States: 1963–1999. Clin Pharmacol Ther 2001; 69 (5): 286–96PubMedCrossRef
16.
go back to reference Lichtenberg FR, Philipson TJ. The dual effects of intellectual property regulations: within- and between-patent competition in the US pharmaceuticals industry. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series, October 2002, Working Paper 9303 [online]. Available from URL: http://www.nber.org/papers/w9303.pdf [Accessed September 14, 2004] Lichtenberg FR, Philipson TJ. The dual effects of intellectual property regulations: within- and between-patent competition in the US pharmaceuticals industry. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series, October 2002, Working Paper 9303 [online]. Available from URL: http://​www.​nber.​org/​papers/​w9303.​pdf [Accessed September 14, 2004]
17.
go back to reference Cockburn IM. The changing structure of the pharmaceutical industry. Health Aff 2004 Jan/Feb; 23 (1): 10–22CrossRef Cockburn IM. The changing structure of the pharmaceutical industry. Health Aff 2004 Jan/Feb; 23 (1): 10–22CrossRef
18.
go back to reference DiMasi JA. New drug innovation and pharmaceutical industry structure: trends in the output of pharmaceutical firms. Drug Inf J 2000; 34 (4): 1169–94CrossRef DiMasi JA. New drug innovation and pharmaceutical industry structure: trends in the output of pharmaceutical firms. Drug Inf J 2000; 34 (4): 1169–94CrossRef
19.
go back to reference Danzon PM, Pauly MV. Health insurance and the growth in pharmaceutical expenditures. J Law Econ 2002; 45 (Oct-): 587–613CrossRef Danzon PM, Pauly MV. Health insurance and the growth in pharmaceutical expenditures. J Law Econ 2002; 45 (Oct-): 587–613CrossRef
20.
go back to reference Baumol WJ. The free-market innovation machine: analyzing the growth miracle of capitalism. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2002: 33 Baumol WJ. The free-market innovation machine: analyzing the growth miracle of capitalism. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2002: 33
21.
go back to reference Lichtenberg FR. Are the benefits of newer drugs worth their cost? Evidence from the 1996 MEPS. Health Aff 2001 Sep/Oct; 20 (5): 241–51CrossRef Lichtenberg FR. Are the benefits of newer drugs worth their cost? Evidence from the 1996 MEPS. Health Aff 2001 Sep/Oct; 20 (5): 241–51CrossRef
23.
go back to reference Lichtenberg FR. The impact of new drug launches on longevity: evidence from longitudinal disease-level data from 52 countries, 1982–2001. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series, June 2003, Working Paper 9754 [online]. Available from URL: http://www.nber.org/papers/w9754.pdf [Accessed September 14, 2004] Lichtenberg FR. The impact of new drug launches on longevity: evidence from longitudinal disease-level data from 52 countries, 1982–2001. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series, June 2003, Working Paper 9754 [online]. Available from URL: http://​www.​nber.​org/​papers/​w9754.​pdf [Accessed September 14, 2004]
24.
go back to reference Angell M. The pharmaceutical industry: to whom is it accountable? New Engl J Med 2000; 342 (25): 1902–4PubMedCrossRef Angell M. The pharmaceutical industry: to whom is it accountable? New Engl J Med 2000; 342 (25): 1902–4PubMedCrossRef
25.
go back to reference Relman AS, Angell M. America’s other drug problem: how the drug industry distorts medicine and politics. The New Republic 2002; 587 (4); 27–41 Relman AS, Angell M. America’s other drug problem: how the drug industry distorts medicine and politics. The New Republic 2002; 587 (4); 27–41
26.
go back to reference Editorial. Comparing prescription drugs. New York Times 2003 Aug 27; Sect. A: 20 Editorial. Comparing prescription drugs. New York Times 2003 Aug 27; Sect. A: 20
27.
go back to reference Goozner M. Prescription for reform. Washington Post 2003 Dec 1; Sect. A: 23 Goozner M. Prescription for reform. Washington Post 2003 Dec 1; Sect. A: 23
28.
go back to reference F-D-C Reports. AHRQ comparative study agenda should emphasize lit reviews — McClellan. Pink Sheet 2004 May 31; 66 (22): 26–7 F-D-C Reports. AHRQ comparative study agenda should emphasize lit reviews — McClellan. Pink Sheet 2004 May 31; 66 (22): 26–7
29.
go back to reference Henderson R, Cockburn I. Scale, scope, and spillovers: the determinants of research productivity in drug discovery. RAND J Econ Spring 1996; 27 (1): 32–59CrossRef Henderson R, Cockburn I. Scale, scope, and spillovers: the determinants of research productivity in drug discovery. RAND J Econ Spring 1996; 27 (1): 32–59CrossRef
30.
go back to reference F-D-C Reports. CMS will focus on value, not price, of medicines, McClellan pledges. Pink Sheet 2004 Mar 29; 66 (13): 9–10 F-D-C Reports. CMS will focus on value, not price, of medicines, McClellan pledges. Pink Sheet 2004 Mar 29; 66 (13): 9–10
Metadata
Title
The economics of follow-on drug research and development
Trends in entry rates and the timing of development
Authors
Joseph A. DiMasi, Ph.D.
Cherie Paquette
Publication date
01-10-2004
Publisher
Springer International Publishing
Published in
PharmacoEconomics / Issue Special Issue 2/2004
Print ISSN: 1170-7690
Electronic ISSN: 1179-2027
DOI
https://doi.org/10.2165/00019053-200422002-00002

Other articles of this Special Issue 2/2004

PharmacoEconomics 2/2004 Go to the issue

EditorialNotes

Foreword