The American Psychiatric Association (APA) has updated its Privacy Policy and Terms of Use, including with new information specifically addressed to individuals in the European Economic Area. As described in the Privacy Policy and Terms of Use, this website utilizes cookies, including for the purpose of offering an optimal online experience and services tailored to your preferences.

Please read the entire Privacy Policy and Terms of Use. By closing this message, browsing this website, continuing the navigation, or otherwise continuing to use the APA's websites, you confirm that you understand and accept the terms of the Privacy Policy and Terms of Use, including the utilization of cookies.

×
Other ArticleFull Access

Cost-Utility Analysis in Depression: The McSad Utility Measure for Depression Health States

Abstract

Cost-utility analysis, used increasingly over the past decade to analyze costs and effects in treating physical diseases, has received little attention in psychiatry. This article briefly introduces the concepts and methods of utility measurement and illustrates it using depression as an example. The authors describe the McSad health state classification system for depression, a direct utility measure for depression, and report results of an application of McSad among 105 patients who had a recent history of depression. Utility measures express patient preferences for specific health states on a scale ranging from 0, representing death, to 1, representing perfect health. These scores provide the weights used to calculate the number of quality-adjusted life-years gained by an intervention or service. McSad allows a patient's depression health state to be classified according to level of functioning in six dimensions of depression and to be compared with other hypothetical depression health states in order to produce utility scores indicating the patient's relative preferences.

Psychiatrists and other mental health professionals concerned with the costs and effects of psychiatric services need to be familiar with the techniques of economic analysis so that they can understand and apply the results of economic evaluations in their work (1,2). Cost-utility analysis is one useful form of economic evaluation (3,4). In this approach, the costs of an intervention or service are considered in relation to its effects, expressed as the number of quality-adjusted life-years (QALYs) gained. QALYs are calculated by adjusting the length of time to be spent in a specific health state (typically the patient's life expectancy) by the quality of that health state. These quality-adjustment weights are obtained by using utility measurement techniques.

Over the past decade utility measurement instruments have been used to obtain quality-adjustment weights for health states associated with a broad range of physical diseases. However, they have had little or no application to health states associated with psychiatric disorders. Our aim in this paper is to introduce mental health professionals to the concepts and methods of utility measurement. First, utility theory and general issues related to measurement are summarized. Next, the utility approach is illustrated using depression as an example. Utility measures are contrasted with traditional measures of depression symptoms, and the experience to date with utility measures of depression is reviewed. To provide an example, we describe the design of the McSad health state classification system for depression, a direct utility measure for depression, and report the results obtained in a patient survey using McSad.

Utility theory andmeasurement methods

Utility measures are derived from economic and decision theory, specifically von Neumann-Morgenstern utility theory, which describes decision making under conditions of risk and uncertainty (5,6,7). The objective of the utility measurement process is to determine the score for a specific state of health on the utility scale, which ranges from 0, indicating death, to 1, indicating perfect health. The utility score an individual assigns to a given health state reflects the desirability or preference that person has for that health state relative to perfect health and death—that is, its utility.

Utility scores—often referred to simply as utilities—are obtained through specialized measurement techniques: the standard gamble, the rating scale, and the time trade-off. The standard gamble and the rating scale methods are discussed below. The time trade-off approach is described elsewhere (4). The standard gamble is the classical approach to utility measurement (4,8) because preferences are measured under uncertainty—that is, risk or probabilities are involved in the utility measurement question. The rating scale and time trade-off methods can also be used, although these methods produce values, not utilities, because uncertainty and risk are not involved in the measurement process. Rating scale values can be transformed with a power curve calculation to allow them to be interpreted as utilities (8,9). For the time trade-off approach, however, no conversion method is currently available.

The distinction between utilities obtained with the standard gamble and values obtained with the rating scale or time trade-off techniques is important. Value measurement is founded on psychological scaling (10,11), whereas utility measurement is founded on von Neumann-Morgenstern utility theory. Empirically, the differences are systematic (for health states, utilities exceed values) and can be quite large (3). In health applications, utilities are more appropriate than values because von Neumann-Morgenstern utility theory addresses decision making in the face of uncertainty. Clearly, health care decisions often involve uncertainties, and sometimes large uncertainties.

Utilities can be obtained directly (1) or indirectly (4,12). McSad is a direct measure in which rating scale and standard gamble techniques are used in a structured, interviewer-administered questionnaire to obtain utilities for specific health states. Respondents are asked about their own state of health and about other hypothetical health states that they may or may not have experienced in the past, selected according to the research objectives of the investigator. McSad is focused on depression and hence uses hypothetical depression health states.

Alternatively, utilities can be obtained indirectly by classifying an individual's health status into a multiattribute health status classification system (12,13). The utility for a specific health state is then calculated using the scoring formula for that system. However, no such system is currently available for converting classifications of psychiatric disorders into utility scores.

Utility measurement in depression

The information provided by utility scores is complementary to existing measures of the presence and severity of psychiatric symptoms, such as the Hamilton Depression Rating Scale (14), the Montgomery-Asberg Depression Rating Scale (15), the Beck Depression Inventory (16), and the Center for Epidemiologic Studies Depression Scale (17). However, these instruments differ from the utility approach in a fundamental way. The scores they produce reflect the presence and severity of depressive symptoms, as defined by the item content, the scaling method, and the rater (physician, trained interviewer, or patient).

In contrast, utility scores measure the desirability or preference a patient has for depression as a health state, relative to other health states, on the utility scale. For example, two respondents might have identical depression severity ratings on the Hamilton Depression Rating Scale. However, when they are asked to rate their own current health states using utility techniques, the desirability or preference they assign on the scale may differ significantly. In an evaluation of the impact of a drug treatment for depression, scores on a utility measure and on a symptom rating scale may lead to different conclusions about the benefit of the treatment.

Relatively little attention has been given to utility measurement in depression. Scores for depression health states are available from only a few surveys of representative samples of the general population using methods with demonstrated reliability and validity. In one study, a health state characterized as a three-month episode of depression was assessed using the time trade-off method and received a value of .44 (18). In another study, again using the time trade-off method, a health state described as "being anxious or depressed some or a good bit of the time and having very few friends and little contact with others" received a score of .45 (8). In a third study, the health state "extremely fretful, angry, irritable, or depressed usually requiring hospitalization or psychiatric institutional care" received an indirect utility score of .50 using a multiattribute health status classification system (19).

Utility scores provide the weights required to calculate quality-adjusted life years (QALYs) for cost-utility analysis. The following is a simplified example of how they are used. Utility scores obtained with McSad (discussed in more detail below) were .59 for mild depression and .32 for moderate depression. For an individual who can be expected to live another 20 years, the QALY figure associated with spending the entire 20 years in the moderate depression health state would be 6.6 years (20 x .32).

In contrast, the QALY figure associated with spending the entire period in the mild depression health state would be 11.8 years (20 x .59). Thus 5.2 quality-adjusted life years are gained as a result of an intervention that moves an individual from the moderate to the mild depression health state. The cost of treatment per QALY gained is then calculated. Cost can be calculated from at least three different perspectives—cost to the patient and the family, cost to the health care system, and cost to society. Torrance (3) provides a detailed discussion of the use and calculation of QALYs.

To our knowledge, only three cost-utility analyses of treatment for depression have been published. In one of these studies, utility values were generated by a panel of physicians rather than by patients or representative samples of the general population or caregivers (20). The authors of the study provided very few details about the methods they used to obtain the utility scores. Elsewhere it has been shown that physicians tend to assign higher utility scores than patients to a given health state (21). Another investigator used estimated values drawn from a literature review (22).

A third study included standard gamble utilities obtained from a sample of patients at two sites who had completed eight weeks of antidepressant therapy (23). Untreated depression received a standard gamble utility score of .30. The other states assessed described short-term treatment with three different drugs. The authors provided very little information about the content of the health state descriptions and how they were developed. Also, if the patients were symptomatic, the scores obtained may have been biased downward.

Mean utility scores can be compared between treatment groups to evaluate differential treatment effects on patient preferences for the outcomes produced. For example, the mean utility score for a new treatment might be in the neighborhood of .60, which is consistent with mild depression (as suggested by the initial results with McSad presented below). If the existing standard treatment resulted in a mean utility score around .30 (consistent with moderate depression, based on the mean McSad utility score for this state), then we could conclude that, on average, the new treatment moves patients from moderate depression to mild depression. In the absence of clinical benchmarks along the utility scale, a difference of .10 on the scale is the minimum to be considered a clinically important difference (4).

The McSad utility measure for depression health states

In this section we provide an example of a direct utility measure of depression health states—McSad. First we describe the instrument itself. Then we report utility scores for depression health states obtained in a patient survey using McSad.

McSad was designed to measure utility scores for four depression health states: the respondent's self-reported health state and three clinical marker health states of untreated depression. Clinical marker health states are hypothetical states that the respondent may or may not have experienced. The three included in McSad, which describe untreated mild, moderate, and severe unipolar depression, provide utility scores for clinically important levels of untreated depression. These clinical marker health states were constructed using items from the six dimensions listed in Table 1. They can be used as benchmarks, or anchors, along the utility scale to aid in the clinical interpretation of utility scores (24).

To create descriptions of health states requires multiattribute classification systems that make explicit the dimensions of health and then define them in terms of levels of functioning (12,13). However, existing multiattribute systems are of limited usefulness for describing depression health states because they were developed to describe general health status and physical function (12,13). The Health Utilities Index, for example, includes eight dimensions: vision, hearing, speech, ambulation, dexterity, emotion, cognition, and pain (13).

To describe depression health states, we developed the initial draft of the McSad depression health state classification system. The final version of the system was based on validity assessments by clinicians involved in the care of depressed patients. A full description of the validity assessment methods we used is available elsewhere (25).

As shown in Table 1, McSad consists of six dimensions: emotion, self-appraisal, cognition, physiology, behavior, and role function. The selection of these dimensions was guided by the DSM-III-R criteria for major unipolar depression. Each dimension is operationalized by specific components designed to capture its essence in depression. For example, mood and ability to experience pleasure are the components of the emotion dimension.

Four levels of functioning are defined for each dimension, reflecting absence of dysfunction or mild, moderate, or severe dysfunction. For example, having no dysfunction on the emotion dimension is described as "Mood is normal. Enjoy life with its usual ups and downs." Mild emotional dysfunction is described as "Feel more down (or sad, blue, depressed) than usual and don't enjoy things as usual."

Respondents' self-reported health state is obtained at the start of the McSad interview by presenting them with a checklist of the McSad items and asking them to identify their level of functioning on each of the six dimensions during a specified period preceding the interview, usually seven days. The completed checklist is then used in the McSad interview along with the three McSad clinical marker health states—descriptions of untreated mild, moderate, and severe depression, presented to respondents on printed cards.

The McSad interview is a face-to-face interview with a trained interviewer. Respondents are asked a series of questions, in two parts, about the four health states. In part one, the questions about the health states are derived from the rating scale method, and in part two, from the standard gamble.

The rating scale approach is presented as a feeling thermometer. Respondents rank the health states by preference, relative to one another and to the anchor states. The top anchor of the thermometer, assigned a value of 100, is defined as the most preferred health state (perfect health). The bottom anchor, assigned a value of 0, is defined as the least preferred health state (death). In this exercise, respondents are asked to imagine living in each of the four health states without change for the rest of their lives. They are then asked to place the states of health along the scale in order of preference, spacing them at intervals that reflect the differences in the strength of preference the respondent feels for them. A utility score between 1 and 0 is computed for each health state.

The standard gamble is presented in the interview as two choices. Choice A, the uncertain choice, contains two possible health state outcomes, perfect health and death, which have the probabilities of p and 1-p, respectively, of occurring. Choice B is the certain choice; it includes only one possible health state or outcome—moderate depression, for example, as described in the corresponding clinical marker health state. The two health states are specified to last the same amount of time. The interviewer varies the probability (p) in choice A systematically until the respondent is indifferent between the uncertain and the certain choice.

For example, respondents are asked whether they would prefer to live the remainder of their lives in the moderate depression health state (choice B) or would prefer a lottery (choice A) in which they would have, say, a probability of .9 of having perfect health for the remainder of their lives and a probability of .1 of immediate death. If a respondent prefers choice A with these odds, the interviewer then reverses the question. Respondents are asked whether they would prefer to live the remainder of their lives in the moderate depression health state or would prefer a lottery in which they would have a probability of .9 of immediate death and a probability of .1 of having perfect health for the remainder of their lives. This reversal in the questioning, known as the Ping-Pong approach, is used to minimize measurement bias.

The interviewer then shifts the odds to a probability of .8 of perfect health and a probability of .2 of immediate death, and then again reverses the question. If the respondent still prefers the lottery, the odds are changed to probabilities of .7 and .3, and so on, until the respondent's preference for the lottery is the same as for a health state of moderate depression. Likewise, if the respondent prefers choice B at the outset, the odds are shifted in the opposite direction until the preferences are equal. The probability (p) at this indifference point is the utility score for the health state in choice B. The interviewer then goes to other health states, in random order, for choice B.

Application of McSad

McSad was applied in a cross-sectional survey of 105 patients who had experienced at least one episode of major, unipolar depression in the past two years but were currently in remission. Patients were recruited in 1995 from four psychiatric outpatient clinics linked to the Faculty of Health Sciences at McMaster University in Hamilton, Ontario. Of 121 patients referred, 117 met the inclusion criteria, and 112 agreed to participate. Of these, seven patients were excluded after the interview: five whose results were positive on a screen for relapse and two who were deemed ineligible because of physical handicap and hospital admission for depression, conditions that might bias the utility scores downward.

Interviews were audio-recorded and were spot-checked at regular intervals by a member of the research team. All interviews were completed, and the mean±SD interview duration was 52.6±8.4 minutes. Eighty-nine percent of the respondents were judged by the interviewer to have fully comprehended the interview, and all respondents were judged to have been fully cooperative.

The mean±SD age of the respondents was 41.7±8.7 years. Females constituted 74 percent of the sample, 62 percent reported English as their ethnic identity, and 68 percent were engaged in either full-time or part-time employment outside the home. Sixty-nine percent reported that they had completed high school, and 19 percent had a university degree. Sixty-six percent of the respondents reported that they first sought treatment for their depression within the past four years, 71 percent had experienced more than one episode of depression, and 66 percent reported that they had experienced severe depression as described by the McSad severe depression health state. Sixty-six percent of the respondents were currently taking antidepressant medication.

Table 2 shows the mean utility scores and 95 percent confidence intervals for the McSad depression health states. The three clinical marker states were measured using a six-month duration, and the self-reported health state and severe depression were measured using a lifetime duration. The respondent's self-reported health state appears not to have influenced the scores assigned to the hypothetical health states; the Pearson correlation coefficients between the self-reported health states and the hypothetical health states were all below .15 (p>.05). The order of the mean scores for the clinical markers is consistent with the rankings of mild (.59), moderate (.32), and severe (.09). The difference in means between mild and moderate depression is .27 (t= 15.16, p<.05), and the difference between moderate and severe depression is .23 (t=12.92, p<.05).

Conclusions

To date, utility measures have had little or no application to psychiatric disorders. The few cost-utility analyses that have been conducted on depression have relied primarily on expert opinion to obtain the utility values required. The McSad system provides an example of how utility approaches can be applied in psychiatric disorders and used to evaluate the incremental utility gain associated with a psychiatric intervention. The utility scores obtained with McSad for the untreated mild, moderate, and severe clinical marker health states show that depression is in fact associated with poor health-related quality of life. Compared with published utilities for chronic physical diseases, mild depression is in the same range as kidney dialysis; the utility for moderate depression is below that reported for "being blind, deaf, or dumb" (9).

Further research is required to gain a better understanding of the patient preferences explored in this study. The generalizability of the McSad depression utility scores reported here is uncertain. The survey respondents were recruited from four psychiatric outpatient clinics linked to an academic medical center. The extent to which these respondents are representative of all patients with a history of major unipolar depression who meet the study inclusion criteria is not known. In addition, the scores assigned by members of the general public, caregivers, or relatives of patients with depression may differ from the scores obtained from the patients themselves. Such potential differences merit further study.

Instruments such as McSad can be used to obtain the utility scores needed for cost-utility studies and medical decision-making models in major unipolar depression. Moreover, the methods used to develop McSad provide a foundation for realizing the broader goal of developing a method to convert psychiatric classifications into utility scores. As a first step, we developed a health state classification system specific to depression. In future work, the methods used for McSad can be extended to other psychiatric disorders.

Dr. Bennett, Dr. Torrance, and Dr. Boyle are affiliated with the department of clinical epidemiology and biostatistics at McMaster University in Hamilton, Ontario, and Dr. Guscott is affiliated with the department of psychiatry of the University of Toronto in Toronto, Ontario. Dr. Torrance is also affiliated with the Centre for Health Economics and Policy Analysis and the School of Business at McMaster University, and Dr. Boyle is also with the department of psychiatry. Address correspondence to Dr. Bennett, Department of Clinical Epidemiology and Biostatistics, Room 3V43D, McMaster University, 1200 Main Street West, Hamilton, Ontario, Canada L8N 3Z5 (e-mail, ).

Table 1. The six dimensions of the McSad depression health state classification system with four levels of functioning indicating the absence of dysfunction and mild, moderate, and severe dysfunction

Table 1.

Table 1. The six dimensions of the McSad depression health state classification system with four levels of functioning indicating the absence of dysfunction and mild, moderate, and severe dysfunction

Enlarge table

Table 2. McSad depression health state utility scores for a sample of 105 patients with at least one episode of major unipolar depression

Table 2.

Table 2. McSad depression health state utility scores for a sample of 105 patients with at least one episode of major unipolar depression

Enlarge table

References

1. Neumann PJ, Hermann RC, Berenbaum PA, et al: Methods of cost-effectiveness analysis in the assessment of new drugs for Alzheimer's disease. Psychiatric Services 48:1440-1444, 1997LinkGoogle Scholar

2. Fisher WH: Cost-outcomes methods for mental health (book review). Psychiatric Services 50:569, 1999LinkGoogle Scholar

3. Torrance GW: Designing and conducting cost-utility analysis, in Quality of Life and Pharmacoeconomics in Clinical Trials. Edited by Spilker B. Philadelphia, Lippincott-Raven, 1996Google Scholar

4. Bennett KJ, Torrance GW: Measuring health state preferences and utilities: rating scale, time trade-off, and standard gamble techniques, ibidGoogle Scholar

5. Von Neumann J, Morgenstern O: Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press, 1944Google Scholar

6. Holloway CA: Decision Making Under Uncertainty: Models and Choices. Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall, 1979Google Scholar

7. Keeney RL, Raiffa H: Decisions With Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value Trade-Offs. New York, Wiley, 1976Google Scholar

8. Torrance GW: Measurement of health state utilities for economic appraisal: a review. Journal of Health Economics 5:1-30, 1986Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

9. Torrance GW, Boyle MH, Horwood SP: Application of multi-attribute utility theory to measure social preferences for health states. Operations Research 30:1043-1069, 1982Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

10. Torrance GW, Zhang Y, Feeny D, et al: Multi-attribute preference functions for a comprehensive health status classification system. Centre for Health Economics and Policy Analysis Working Paper Series, no 92-18. Hamilton, Ontario, McMaster University, 1992Google Scholar

11. Von Winterfeldt D, Edwards W: Decision Analysis and Behavioural Research. Cambridge, England, Cambridge University Press, 1986Google Scholar

12. Feeny D, Furlong W, Boyle M, et al: Multi-attribute health status classification systems: Health Utilities Index. Pharmacoeconomics 7:490-502, 1995Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

13. Torrance GW, Furlong W, Feeny D, et al: Multi-attribute preference functions: Health Utilities Index. Pharmacoeconomics 7:503-520, 1995Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

14. Hamilton M: A rating scale for depression. Journal of Neurology, Neurosurgery, and Psychiatry 23:56-62, 1960Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

15. Montgomery SA, Asberg M: A new depression scale designed to be sensitive to change. British Journal of Psychiatry 134:382-389, 1979Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

16. Beck AT, Ward CH, Mendelson M, et al: An inventory for measuring depression. Archives of General Psychiatry 4:561-571, 1961Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

17. Radloff LS: The CES-D scale: a self-report depression scale for research in the general population. Applied Psychological Measurement 1:385-401, 1977CrossrefGoogle Scholar

18. Sackett DL, Torrance GW: The utility of different health states as perceived by the general public. Journal of Chronic Diseases 31:697-704, 1978Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

19. Torrance GW, Feeny DH, Furlong WJ, et al: Multi-attribute utility function for a comprehensive health status classification system: Health Utilities Index Mark 2. Medical Care 34:702-722, 1996Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

20. Hatziandreu EJ, Brown RE, Revicki D, et al: Cost utility of maintenance treatment of recurrent depression with sertraline versus episodic treatment with dothiepin. Pharmacoeconomics 5:249-264, 1994Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

21. Froberg D, Kane R: Methodology for measuring health state preferences: III. population and context effects. Journal of Clinical Epidemiology 42:585-592, 1989Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

22. Kamlet MS, Paul N, Greenhouse J, et al: Cost utility analysis of maintenance treatment for recurrent depression. Controlled Clinical Trials 16:17-40, 1995Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

23. Revicki DA, Brown RE, Palmer W, et al: Modelling the cost effectiveness of antidepressant treatment in primary care. Pharmacoeconomics 8:524-540, 1995Crossref, MedlineGoogle Scholar

24. Bennett KJ, Torrance GW, Tugwell P: Methodologic challenges in the development of utility measures of health related quality of life in rheumatoid arthritis. Controlled Clinical Trials 12(suppl):118S-128S, 1991Google Scholar

25. Bennett KJ, Torrance GW, Boyle MH, et al: McSad Mental Health State Utilities: Results of a Survey in Major, Unipolar Depression. Centre for Health Economics and Policy Analysis Working Paper Series, no 96-20. Hamilton, Canada, McMaster University, 1996Google Scholar